SciELO - Scientific Electronic Library Online

 
vol.1 número1A note on the consensus time of mean-field majority-rule dynamicsAnswer to the Commentary on “A note on the consensus time of mean-field majority-rule dynamics” índice de autoresíndice de materiabúsqueda de artículos
Home Pagelista alfabética de revistas  

Servicios Personalizados

Revista

Articulo

Indicadores

  • No hay articulos citadosCitado por SciELO

Links relacionados

  • No hay articulos similaresSimilares en SciELO

Compartir


Papers in physics

versión On-line ISSN 1852-4249

Pap. Phys. vol.1 no.1 La Plata jun. 2009

 

 

Commentary on “A note on the consensus time of mean-field majority-rule dynamics”

 

Hugo Fort,1

*E-mail: hugo@fisica.edu.uy
Instituto de Física, Facultad de Ciencias, Universidad de la República, Iguá 4225, CP 11.400 Montevideo, Uruguay.

In this Commentary, I review the article by D. H. Zanette on the consensus time of mean-field majority-rule dynamics [1]. The paper identifies two different regimes for the mean field (MF) ver-sion of the majority-rule (MR) opinion dynamics, characterized by different dependences on the population size N. In one of them, corresponding to gradual persuasion, the typical known logarithmic dependence is observed. The novelty appears in the alternative regime, associated with very drastic events, which is governed by a power law. In this Commentary, I point out a couple of minor points that, in my opinion, deserve further clarification. I also make some general remarks and briefly discuss some features which can be incorporated in order to use the model in more realistic contexts.

The author addresses the problem of the depen-dence of the consensus time with the population size in a mean field (MF) version of the majority-rule (MR) opinion dynamics. The size of the group of agents selected at each evolution step, G, is drawn from a probability distribution pG, which for large G decays as a power law.

The main result is that, for MFMR, the consen-sus time S exhibits two distinct regimes, charac-terized by different dependences on the population size N. If the exponent of pG is larger than 2, S has a dependence of the kind N logN which is already known from analytical results for constant G. On the other hand, if the exponent of the distribution of group sizes is less or equal than 2, the dependence of S on N is also given by a power law. It is interest-ing that the two regimes are related to two different mechanisms of consensus attainment: gradual per-suasion versus drastic large-G events which involve the whole population at a single evolution step. Some points that would need further clarificationare:

a.  The equivalence of the MFMR to a random walk under the action of a force field, mentioned at the end of page 1, is an interesting issue. For those who are not experts on this area I think that it deserves a more detailed explanation; in-deed, the walk has variable step length since only the agents with the minority opinion flip, and the direction of the force seems to exhibit a sort of persistence.

b.  What is the rationale for considering values of G larger than the population size? In fact, the maximum physically possible G is N. Perhaps it is for technical reasons or difficulties implement-ing the constraint that G cannot be greater than N?

Some considerations, a little beyond the scope of the majority-rule opinion model, on features concerning realistic situations which are not included in this model:

1.  Individual heterogeneity. There are always in-dividuals who are not susceptible to the MR for their convictions, or by necessity, and resist the majority opinion. In addition, there are in-dividuals who can change their mind not only by following herd behaviour but also through other mechanisms like learning from experience, etc.

2.  Space. The spatial structure might have a rel-evant effect on the MR opinion dynamics. Has this been studied? In general, it turns out that spatial correlation may introduce important differences in agent based models.

3.  Chance. The application of the MR is completely deterministic. The effects of introducing a stochastic component is something worth exploring. For example, in the form that some of the individuals in the minority of G do not flip or some in the majority suffer spontaneous flips.

4.  Population dynamics. For long times it seems unavoidable to consider births and deaths, this turnover population seems to be a dynamic source for the opinion formation. Maybe this could be implemented by a noise term like the one mentioned above.

5.  Opinion Formation Factors. Mass media signals, advertising and propaganda operating over the individuals play an important role in opinion formation and can have an important impact. It seems that this could be modeled by external fields.

 

[1] D H Zanette, A note on the consensus time of mean-field majority-rule dynamics, Pap. Phys. 1, 010002 (2009).

Creative Commons License Todo el contenido de esta revista, excepto dónde está identificado, está bajo una Licencia Creative Commons